▲ | catigula 14 hours ago | |
We live in the age of AI, it takes approximately 2-3 minutes to get a condensed report on why your paper is misleading or incorrect: Control group mismatch: Treats non-profits as a clean counterfactual for for-profits, but the sectors have very different occupational mixes and shocks—so the triple-diff can pick up sectoral composition, not policy. Short pre-trend: Only a tiny non-binding window to test parallel trends → weak pre-trend evidence. Approvals ≠ demand: Uses approved H-1Bs (not applications), so results reflect rationed outcomes and USCIS processing quirks, not employer demand. Strong wage-equalization assumption: Identification leans on wages equalizing across very different employers; if sector premia move (e.g., recession), estimates drift. Relative, not absolute, effect: The estimate is “for-profit vs. non-profit”; if non-profits expand (cap-exempt), the “effect” can be reallocation, not a true for-profit decline. Recession confound: Lottery years coincide with 2008–09; macro shocks can differentially hit new vs. established hires across sectors. Noisy worker/firm measures: Experience is imputed (age minus stylized schooling ages); employer names are inconsistently harmonized → concentration trends may be artifacts; “large firm” cutoff is arbitrary. Wage results are shaky: Based on offer wages (not realized), trimmed, and imprecise—tail stories are fragile. Placebo underpowered/misaligned: Native “no effect” test is noisy and not analogous to “new vs. established” H-1Bs, so it’s weak evidence on substitutability. Ignores geography: Cells are national; regional wage floors and local cycles could drive composition shifts. Net: clever design but brittle; treat findings as suggestive reallocation under approvals data, not clean causal effects on demand, wages, or “top talent.” |